LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Blog Team

January 10th, 2014

Parties’ views on decentralisation are determined by their economic and cultural positions

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Blog Team

January 10th, 2014

Parties’ views on decentralisation are determined by their economic and cultural positions

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Decentralisation has been one of the principal forces driving constitutional change in European democracies over the past few decades. Using data covering 284 parties in 31 separate countries, Simon Toubeau and Markus Wagner assess the link between policies on decentralisation, and parties’ ideology on economic and cultural matters. They illustrate that parties form their stance on decentralisation with close reference to their economic and cultural value positions. This effect is influenced, however, by factors such as the degree of self-rule afforded to regions, the existence of regional economic disparities, and the ideological distance of regionalist parties at the national level.

In Europe, we are aware of how the EU has transformed the nation state, but in many countries another source of transformation has been equally powerful: the process of decentralisation. This process has gathered pace in recent years. In November 2011, Belgium reformed its constitution for the sixth time to accommodate the demands of assertive Flemish nationalist parties. In the UK, the recommendations of the Calman Commission found their way into the Scotland Act 2012, which provides the Scottish Government with greater tax-varying powers. In countries such as Germany, Italy and Austria, long-standing debates have been ongoing over how much financial autonomy regions should have. These processes are present elsewhere as well. In recent decades, established democracies have undertaken constitutional reforms that have transferred political power away from the national level and towards the regional level of government.

Scottish Parliament, Edinburgh (Credit: David Baron, CC-BY-SA-3.0)
Scottish Parliament, Edinburgh (Credit: David Baron, CC-BY-SA-3.0)

However, what is often overlooked is that these decentralisation processes are initiated, driven and shaped by state-wide political parties. These parties adopt distinct views on territorially-based political struggles. In elections, they compete on the question of whether or not to decentralise power and when they form national governments, they take decisions to transfer power to regions. This means that understanding their stance towards decentralisation is crucial for understanding when and how the process unfolds. But what lies behind state-wide parties’ positions on this issue? What we are interested in uncovering is what shapes the position that parties adopt towards the assignment of power to regions.

We argue that parties’ positions on the issue of decentralisation are related to their ideological beliefs. More specifically, their positions are shaped by the preferences they hold on the two key underlying components of ideology: economy and culture. This is due to the fact that decentralisation is a political issue related to the nature of governance which, as Liesbet Hooghe and Gary Marks have suggested, raises questions of efficiency and redistribution on the one hand and of identity on the other.

Let us look first at the effect of economic ideology. Decentralisation can improve the allocation of public goods, so parties on the economic right should prefer decentralisation. At the same time, decentralisation also hinders efforts to redistribute wealth, so parties on the economic left should oppose it. The effect of cultural ideology is quite straightforward: culturally liberal parties should support decentralisation because it recognises diversity. Culturally conservative parties should oppose it, because it erodes national unity.

To test these hypotheses, we used data on party positions from an expert survey carried out by Ken Benoit and Michael Laver.  A party’s position is measured by experts’ assessments: low values indicate that a party ‘opposes’ while high values indicate that a party ‘promotes the decentralisation of administration and decision-making’. To evaluate the effect of a party’s position on the economic and cultural ideological dimensions, we used scales measuring parties’ attitudes towards raising taxes to increase public services and towards personal freedoms and traditional values. The dataset includes 284 parties in 31 countries.

The results of the analysis show that decentralisation does tap into the logics of efficiency and redistribution on the one hand and identity on the other. Parties’ positions on decentralisation are related to both the economic and cultural ideological dimensions.

The effects of these two dimensions are shown in Figure 1. The darker the shaded portion of the graph, the more in favour of decentralisation a party is predicted to be. Our analysis indicates that an economically left-wing, culturally conservative party (A) is expected to be clearly against decentralisation, while its ideological opposite – a culturally liberal, economically right-wing party (B) – is predicted to be strongly in favour of decentralisation. Parties in the diagonal from the bottom left (C) to the top right (D) will adopt moderate positions on decentralisation.

Figure 1: Decentralisation positions by ideological dimension

Note: The vertical axis indicates cultural positions on a numerical scale, with low values being the most ‘liberal’ and high values being the most ‘conservative’.  The horizontal axis indicates left/right positions, with low values being the most left-wing and high values being the most right-wing. The figure is shaded to indicate the degree to which a party in a given position would be expected to favour decentralisation. The scale associated with this shading is shown in the box on the right, with darker shading (higher values) corresponding with stronger support for decentralisation. See the authors’ longer paper for full calculations

While these results illustrate an important general pattern, our analysis also shows that the structural, institutional and strategic context in which state-wide parties compete shapes whether decentralisation is viewed primarily through an economic or cultural lens.

Two important contextual factors are the degree of regional self-rule and the degree of regional economic disparities. We find that parties’ positions are better explained by their economic ideology when there is a higher degree of regional self-rule and when there are greater regional economic disparities. So, in countries like the United States, where state governments enjoy a substantial degree of autonomy from the federal government, especially in matters like taxation, and where there are important differences in wealth between states, decentralisation raises primarily questions of efficiency and redistribution. Thus, parties’ positions in such countries are strongly influenced by their economic ideology, with left-wing parties like the Democrats being less favourable to decentralisation than economically right-wing parties like the Republicans. This also applies to other countries, such as Belgium, which also have high degrees of self-rule and economic disparities. In contrast, in unitary countries with low levels of regional disparity, like the Netherlands, we expect a much weaker association between parties’ economic ideology and decentralisation.

A final important contextual factor is the presence of regionalist parties such as the Scottish National Party (SNP) in the UK or Nieuw-Vlaamse Allantie (NVA) in Belgium, which articulate demands for territorial autonomy or independence. These parties are an important source of influence on the positions of state-wide parties. The latter will respond to the presence of a regionalist electoral threat by adopting accommodative, pro-decentralist strategies. Regionalist parties present a stronger threat to state-wide parties if they are ideologically similar. In the UK, for example, the Labour party endorsed devolution when threatened by an economically left-wing SNP. Similarly, the right-wing Flemish regionalist parties forced Christian Democratic and Liberal parties to adopt decentralist stances.

This pattern holds in our analysis as well. In Figure 2, we show a state-wide party’s predicted position on decentralisation based on its own economic ideology and the ideological proximity of the regionalist party in economic matters. Low values on the vertical y-axis mean that the regionalist party has a similar economic ideology, while high values mean that it has a different economic ideology. When moving from low to high values on the y-axis, we see that support for decentralisation decreases. So, state-wide parties react strategically to the electoral threat of regionalist parties by taking up more accommodative stances on decentralisation when regionalist parties are ideologically closer.

Figure 2: The effect of regionalist party positions

Note: See the authors’ longer paper for full calculations

In conclusion, parties’ positions on decentralisation are determined by their ideological views on economic and cultural matters, and the influence of economic ideology varies depending on the structural, institutional and strategic context. These findings are important because they show how decentralisation taps into questions of both efficiency and redistribution, as well as identity. These elements are widely visible in contemporary constitutional debates. For example, at the heart of current discussions surrounding the possible independence of Scotland and Catalonia, political parties and electorates are taking stances according not only to how they feel about their regions’ historic identities, but also according to how they view their region’s future economic prosperity.

Please read our comments policy before commenting.

Note: This article gives the views of the authors, and not the position of EUROPP – European Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics.

Shortened URL for this post: http://bit.ly/1aKEoKO

_________________________________

About the authors

Simon Toubeau Centre for Political and Constitutional Studies, Spain
Simon Toubeau is García Pelayo Fellow at Centre for Political and Constitutional Studies (CEPC), Spain. His research focuses on comparative federalism and territorial politics, political parties and party systems, and nationalism

Markus Wagner – University of Vienna
Markus Wagner is an assistant professor in quantitative methods at the Department of Methods in the Social Sciences at the University of Vienna. His research focuses on the role of issues and ideology in party competition and voting behaviour.

About the author

Blog Team

Posted In: Governance and policy evaluation | Markus Wagner | Simon Toubeau

Leave a Reply