LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

BPP Team

March 16th, 2016

Budget 2016: Osborne rolls with the blows, but the politics tramples good economics

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

BPP Team

March 16th, 2016

Budget 2016: Osborne rolls with the blows, but the politics tramples good economics

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

JohnVanReenen238x309John Van Reenen, Director of the Centre for Economic Performance, gives his reaction to the 2016 Budget. The austerity approach continues, despite it having little economic sense. Fuel duty is frozen as a sweetener to his backbenchers. And in terms of the future, Osborne may have spent time outlining the global uncertainties on the long-term economic horizon, but it’s the closer possibility of Brexit which has the potential to be the biggest disruption to his plans.

Four months is a long time in economics. That’s how long it’s been since the Chancellor delivered the Autumn Statement. Then “Lucky George” said he had enough fiscal good news to abandon the plans to radically reduce tax credits to the low paid. Unfortunately, the bad news has come thick and fast since then, causing a downgrade in the growth forecasts in today’s Budget. For example, the 2016 forecast has been cut from 2.4 per cent to 2.0 per cent. But even worse than this was the Office of National Statistics’ discovery that GDP in cash terms was £18bn smaller than they had previously thought. This means less tax revenues are forecast to come in over the next five years.

The Chancellor made three fiscal pledges to cap welfare, reduce debt as a share of GDP and deliver a budget surplus by 2019-20. The first two promises are gone out of the window, so to avoid meeting the third, he announced additional spending cuts today of £3.5 billion. These are all pencilled in for the end of the Parliament and Mr. Osborne is hoping that his luck will return, so they never have to be made. But austerity upon more austerity raises the question of whether there is an alternative to the medicine of more cuts. And the answer is “yes”.

The self-imposed hair shirt of having a 1 per cent surplus by 2020 makes little economic sense. It is calculated as tax receipts minus total public spending. And this is not just current spending on things like the PM’s salary, but also capital spending on projects like High Speed 3 upgrading transport links in the North and the Crossrail 2 rail line in London.  These investments which the National Infrastructure Commission have been pushing make good sense.

But why must such infrastructure projects be financed just by sales of public land and other government assets? The fiscal target should be on balancing the books on current spending over the business cycle – just as it was when the Office of Budget Responsibility was first set up in 2010. Otherwise there will always be too much pressure to under-fund public investment.

If a surplus must be achieved, there is another way of balancing the books, of course which is through tax rises. There have been plenty of these such as insurance premium taxes, the apprenticeship levy and the new sugar tax. But a very sensible way of raising more revenue would have been to raise fuel duty, which has been frozen for the sixth year running. Raising this tax would help tackle climate and would be well-timed as oil prices are so low. But the Chancellor did not restore the fuel duty escalator for one simple reason – fear of upsetting fellow Conservatives in the run up to the EU referendum. So, like the fiscal laws, here is yet another example of one bad policy – the PM’s 2013 decision to a referendum to win back UKIP supporters – delivering even more bad policy. The politics tramples over good economics.

Perhaps the most eye-catching policies were on education. Extending the school day and the pledge to make every school an academy by 2022. Academies are independent from local authority control and can set teachers’ pay and parts of the curriculum. There is strong evidence that the first academies set up to turn around failing schools really worked in improving results for kids. The second wave of academies in 2010, however, were set up much more in wealthier areas and there is scant evidence that they were big improvements over their predecessors.

The Chancellor has warned of big uncertainties on the economic horizon with stock market gyrations and China’s slowdown. But the biggest near term uncertainty is June’s decision over Brexit. He was right to look Tory bench benchers eye to eye and remind them that the OBR forecasts assumed the UK would remain in the EU and that they had warned that leaving “would result in a period of potentially disruptive uncertainty”. That’s an understatement; if Britain votes to leave, it’s going to make the current wobbles feel like the gentle rocking of a baby’s cradle.

__

About the Author

JohnVanReenen238x309John Van Reenen is Director of the Centre for Economic Performance at the London School of Economics.

 

 

Image credit: frankieleon CC BY
Print Friendly, PDF & Email

About the author

BPP Team

Posted In: Economy and Society | Featured | LSE Comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported
This work by British Politics and Policy at LSE is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported.