LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Editor

October 14th, 2016

Democratic Dynasties: State, Party and Family in Contemporary Indian Politics edited by Kanchan Chandra

0 comments | 1 shares

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Editor

October 14th, 2016

Democratic Dynasties: State, Party and Family in Contemporary Indian Politics edited by Kanchan Chandra

0 comments | 1 shares

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Screenshot 2015-07-20 at 23.43.49Democratic Dynasties: State, Party and Family in Contemporary Indian Politics is a new edited volume which draws on original data from India to propose a rethinking of the view that dynastic politics is a violation of democracy, showing that it can also reinforce some aspects of democracy while violating others. Asad Abbasi finds the book deceptively difficult and does not recommend it for casual readers. However, he writes that it does have a straightforward method of analysis which produces interesting conclusions.

Democratic Dynasties: State, Party and Family in Contemporary Indian Politics. Kanchan Chandra (ed). Cambridge University Press. 2016.

democratic-dynastiesWith throne chair on the book cover, and the title Democratic Dynasties, I expected academic version of Game of Thrones: murder, revenge, conspiracy and blood. Instead, I got a lesson in game theory— political parties and politicians are both rational agents who are minimising risk, responding to incentives and in constant quest for stability and maximum returns. Dynastic politics, it follows, is just a rational decision taken by politicians and political parties to get maximum returns in Indian democracy.

For politicians, politics offers a chance for increasing returns at every level (money, status, employment, perks), so those who are powerful get their families into politics too. But if politics turns out to be a bad investment, powerful families will also have members in local, national, legislative and private sectors to spread risk. Even opposition within a family – brother vs. brother or father vs. son – is to diversify risk. In a zero sum game of politics, it’s a win-win strategy. Every political move can be rationally analysed.  It is not politics, it is political science.

The political parties are ‘rational’ institutions too. Parties support dynastic politics to a) to avoid ‘defection’ of party members to rival parties (p. 38), b) to dissuade internal conflicts (p. 41), and c) because in some cases (though not all), dynastic politics help strengthen local ties (p. 262). With these party-based explanations, we find that weakly-organised political parties tend to be more dynastic than organised parties.

Alternative explanations for why parties are dynastic include party size, location and culture. These explanations are succinctly discussed, and then dismissed, by Adam Ziegfeld in chapter four because these alternative explanations cannot replace ‘party-based accounts’ (p. 133).

Democratic Dynasties is deceptively difficult. There are so many parties, politicians, and places. Each chapter has many characters, many tables, and many maps; sometimes, data sets are not adequate enough to get complete answers. For example, it is difficult to know from aggregate data whether voters are voting for dynastic politicians or political parties (p. 45-46). Basically, there is a lot of flicking backwards and forwards so it is not a book to read on your commute.

That said, what impressed me most is the simplicity of the argument and methodology of analysis, which is consistent in every chapter. The method of analysis is straightforward but also produces interesting conclusions.

A history of dynasty in India

The political dynasties that exist in India are a product of democracy in India. Although many people will just think of the Nehru/Gandhi family when dynasty in India is mentioned, it is worth noting that in 2014 twenty percent of Indian parliamentarians were dynastic (p. 15). The first of these “democratic dynasties” emerged sometime around 1960s. In comparison, earlier dynasties, royal dynasts— the aristocratic Maharajas of the pre-democratic India, (covered in Chapter three) made up only two percent of Indian parliamentarians in 2014.

The competition between the old aristocracy and new democrats is traced back to the 1952 Rajasthan election, which is covered in chapter two by Lloyd and Susanne Rudolph. A crucial insight from this chapter is how rivals learnt from each other’s marketing tactics: the aristocracy learned how to make democratic appeals, while the Democrats learned how to draw on tradition and history to garner votes. These royal dynasties have continued to feed on low income, unschooled rural communities ever since but they face complete extinction with urbanisation.

However, the democratic dynasts are going strong, seemingly proving immune to modernisation. In India, data shows that people continue to prefer dynasts over non-dynasts. Why? Chandra admits that they don’t yet have an answer to this important question.

Nor does the book give a clear picture on the pervasiveness of dynastic politics in India. Several chapters, by Basu, Chauchard, Jensenius, suggest that dynastic politics is a big issue in Indian politics, which needs due attention. But Chandra, in the light of the same data, suggests that her previous work may have overestimated prevalence of dynastic politics in India. Looking at 2004 to 2014, Chandra concludes that only five percent of India’s parliamentary constituencies have been ‘continuously represented by dynastic MP’ (p. 49). I was therefore left uncertain as to whether dynastic politics is ascending or receding in India.

Who does dynastic politics benefit?

Dynastic politics has proved to be beneficial for politicians of all groups, although not in equal degree. It has been good for women (p. 49; p. 147), Muslims (p. 50), Scheduled Caste and Scheduled Tribes (p. 205), but, above all, dynastic politics has favoured Forward Castes— already the most dominant group (Chapter 7).

Forward Castes parties only favour Forward Caste members. For anyone familiar with Indian politics, this shouldn’t be surprising but Chandra gives an institutional reason for it: In a Forward Caste party, Forward Caste members are powerful and can grapple party leadership for nomination. To avoid defection and internal politics, party leadership obliges. However, what is surprising is that even in Non-Forward Caste parties (except Muslim parties) Forward Caste members get party preference. The reason: In Non-Forward Caste parties, Forward Caste members are innocuous, and weak. To maintain stability and status quo, and to keep competition at bay, political parties prefer weak politicians and not strong candidates.

In theory, dynastic politics is also a substitute for lacking experience at a local level. In practice, however, this substitution only helps female MPs and Forward Castes (p. 240) according to Bohlken (Chapter 8). Even here, we find that, institutional logic invariably favours Forward Castes. No matter what, Forward Caste parties and politicians always seem to benefit. Is this why dynastic politics continues?

Does dynastic politics favour voters? In the case of women, yes. It is as a result of dynastic politics that more women have entered politics. And data shows that women MPs, dynastic or not, are generally beneficial to female citizens (p. 147). Research on Pakistani women parliamentarians shows women MPs ‘push pro women legislations’ (Bari, 2010) and, despite some women MPs siding with party interests against “women interests”, they are still better at representing women’s concerns than men. The main problem, according to Basu, is that there are still too few women MPs. India has lower number of women MPs than Nepal, Afghanistan, Pakistan and Bangladesh (p. 145). Reservation seats for women will, Basu argue, correct this quantitative marasmus.

Basu’s chapter leaves the reader thinking dynasties and reserved seats can be positive for underrepresented groups, but in chapter 6 Chauchard counters that reserved seats have, in the long run, hindered political relevance of Scheduled Castes (SC) and Scheduled Tribes (ST) and there is no evidence to think that SC/ST dynasties will favour SC/ST people.

It is true that reservation seats have enabled more SC/ST politicians but it is also likely that reservation seats have maimed powerful candidates. The Hawk-Dove matrix can explain this phenomenon. Irrespective of being a Hawk or Dove, given a choice, the political party will choose to negotiate with Dove. The same principle applies to constituents. Voters, irrespective of being hawk or dove, will choose to deal with dove. Chauchard uses this logic and backs it up with evidence. Political parties, even the ones that claim to support SC/ST groups, prefer weak candidates (p. 198). And constituents, due to hierarchical caste system in India, also prefer weaker candidates (p.200). Thus, SC/ST candidates selected by party and voters are all dove i.e. weak candidates.

But even if strong candidates wins, they don’t have legitimacy because candidates who emerge from reservation seats are seen, by political parties and voters, with a negative gaze (p. 201) as if they somehow have not “earned” their place at the table. All this translates into weaker overall position for SC/ST politicians- Symbolic designations and omission from cabinet positions. Only through rise in number of dynasties, Chauchard suggests, SC/ST candidates can achieve some temporary political equity (p. 205).

Conclusion

Given the contrasting positions that Basu and Chauchard take on reservation seats, it would have been interesting to include some element of conversation between the two. A chapter linking dynastic politics and Muslim politicians would also have added another dimension to the book. Exploring in detail how and why Muslim dynasties have continued to exist would be appropriate read, especially when tensions between Hindus and Muslims are simmering.

There are several editing mistakes, for example Sujata Koirala is the female politician from Nepal, and not “Sushila Koirala” (p. 143), while Pakistan’s year of independence is 1947, and not 1952 (p. 145). Although these are harmless, the occasionally added to confusion given the complexity of many of the narratives.

Warning for casual readers: The book is not for you. You need some understanding of Indian political and cultural setting. Even then, not all the characters in the book, and their stories, will stay with you. But the thesis, and method of analysis, both fundamental in understanding dynastic politics, will.

Cover image: Mrs Indira Gandhi with the Hon’ble Pandit Jawaharlal Nehru Prime Minister of India photographed at Palam Aerodrome on October 3, 1949. Credit: Public.Resource.Org CC BY 2.0

This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of the South Asia @ LSE blog, nor of the London School of Economics. Please read our comments policy before posting.

About the Author

Screenshot 2015-07-20 at 23.43.49Asad Abbasi has a Masters degree in Political Economy of Late Development from LSE. Currently, he is researching conceptual frameworks of development.  

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

About the author

Editor

Posted In: Book Reviews | Featured | Gender | LSE | Politics

Jaipur Palace

CONTRIBUTE

South Asia @ LSE welcomes contributions from LSE faculty, fellows, students, alumni and visitors to the school. Please write to southasia@lse.ac.uk with ideas for posts on south Asia-related topics.

Bad Behavior has blocked 5605 access attempts in the last 7 days.