LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Judy Kavanagh

August 8th, 2019

Can robots help fund nicer and more attractive places to live?

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Judy Kavanagh

August 8th, 2019

Can robots help fund nicer and more attractive places to live?

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Robots are going to take our jobs, right?  Well, maybe. The available evidence provides conflicting results. In the US, one new robot reduces employment by 5.6 workers and local wages by about 0.5 per cent according to estimates in Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo’s much cited 2017 paper. In Germany, more robots decrease employment in the manufacturing sector but increase employment in the services sector, suggesting that the spread of robots creates both losers and winners in local labour markets, according to Wolfgang Dauth and his colleagues in a 2018 paper.

So, what’s been happening in Japan, the most robot-dense country in the world? Hot off the press is a paper from Adachi, Kawaguchi and Saito that finds that the employment-to-population ratio (that is, workers per number of local residents) decreased in labour market areas highly exposed to robots in Japan, similar to Acemoglu and Restrepo’s findings for the US. But the decrease in Japan was not caused by a reduction in employment. Overall employment increased, mostly in services-sector jobs (like in Germany) but there was also an increase in the population in the local labour-market area. The employment-to-population ratio decreased not because robots led to a net decrease in jobs, but because the local population increased by a larger amount. This would resolve the apparently inconsistent US and German findings.

Adachi, Kawaguichi and Saito suggest how this could happen. Robots increase productivity, which flows into higher wages and profits — generating more local purchasing power and greater demand for locally produced goods and services. There may be a further effect if the increased economic activity leads to additional tax revenue being spent on local amenities, such as public schools and hospitals (see Moretti, 2010). Good amenities attract more residents (workers and non-working alike). Population growth may be a downstream (third, fourth or fifth order) effect of the robots coming to town. So maybe the finding that more robots in local Japanese labour markets decrease the employment-to-population ratio isn’t that surprising (or negative) after all. It looks like robots can help fund nicer and more attractive places to live.

These findings are about industrial robots, which are easy to measure. They go into well-defined workplaces, usually in manufacturing. The results may not generalise to other automation technologies. This point is made by Acemoglu and Restrepo who also looked at the impact of IT more generally. They found that IT investment, unlike robot investment in the US, did not reduce local employment.

We should be cautious about assuming that local tax and public spending effects found in other places have similar outcomes here. Local government in New Zealand has a smaller scope of responsibilities than local governments in most other countries. This is in part because many of the functions undertaken at the local level in other countries, such as hospitals and schools, are funded centrally in New Zealand and provided through Crown Entities.

Chang-Tai Hsieh and Enrico Moretti recently reported that local government authorities can dampen the effect of high productivity in their cities by restricting growth in housing supply, making housing unaffordable. Such policies are a barrier to population growth and restrict worker access to more abundant job opportunities, including high-productivity work. More on this in a later post.

My main take-out: Robots coming to town have more complex effects on employment and community wellbeing than we might at first expect.

Author’s notes: Fukuoka is the economic centre of the Kyushu region with a high rate of firm start-ups, many service sector firms, and a high-tech manufacturing sector. Sally Davenport attended the ISPIM innovation conference in Fukuoka, Japan in December 2018.

♣♣♣

Notes:

  • This blog post was originally published on the website of the New Zealand Productivity Commission.
  • The post gives the views of its author, not the position of LSE Business Review or the London School of Economics.
  • Feature image (cropped) via MaxPixel, Public domain.
  • Before commenting, please read our Comment Policy

Judy Kavanagh is inquiry director of the New Zealand Productivity Commission. She is an economist with experience in both academia and the public sector. She has had roles in the Ministries of Health and Education and has taught at Canterbury University and Victoria University of Wellington. Her research areas include experimental economics, economic psychology and the organisation of health systems.

 

 

 

About the author

Judy Kavanagh

Judy Kavanagh is inquiry director of the New Zealand Productivity Commission. She is an economist with experience in both academia and the public sector. She has had roles in the Ministries of Health and Education and has taught at Canterbury University and Victoria University of Wellington. Her research areas include experimental economics, economic psychology and the organisation of health systems.

Posted In: Economics and Finance

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.