– China’s economic development model resembles that of Japan over 30 years ago with high savings, and high investment, but with restrained consumption and rigid institutions weighing increasingly on macroeconomic success.
– China’s chronic over-investment and misallocation of capital, particularly in the property sector, pose a potentially bigger economic problem than Japan’s banking crisis in the 1990s.
– China has some advantages over Japan, such as a state-owned financial system that can prevent significant banks from failing and a closed capital account that can protect the country’s banking system and the economy from the risk of significant capital flight. This however might not prevent China from taking the same economic trajectory Japan has.
Over a decade ago as the financial crisis ripped through developed market economies, many commentators wondering how we would ever get out of the mess that followed, resurrected the 1980s pop song, Turning Japanese, by a band called The Vapors. Now, arguably, this was unfair, considering the continuous growth in income per head and the attempts to reform Japan’s economy under the Abe government in the 2010s. Some economists, however, had a different country in mind when they were wondering about the Japan template: China.
This week, as we watch China’s National People’s Congress for signs as to if and how the Chinese Communist Party will come to terms with rising economic headwinds, it is worth remembering why.
Back in the day, few people paid attention. China had launched a pre-emptive stimulus programme in 2008 worth 14 per cent of GDP in the face of the collapse in export orders and coastal province employment. Double-digit growth returned soon afterwards for a while. What was not to like?
And yet, even then, it was clear to students of economic development that China was following precisely the same economic development model that Japan, and some other Asian economies had. Japan especially had carved out its place in the sun as an economic powerhouse through a high saving, high investment economic development model, in which the role of consumption was restrained, and credit creation, non-productive investment, especially in real estate, and net exports were the big drivers of macroeconomic ‘success’.
The share of consumption in the economy never got much over 52 per cent, while in the 6 years to 1991, the share of investment, driven by property, rose by 6 percentage points to 36 per cent.
After the financial crisis, this all began to sound very familiar to China watchers. A recent opinion piece has shed light on some research drawing attention to the Japanification of China, but in fact, this phenomenon has been underway for a while.
The Japan that stalked the global economy in the 1980s and that finally succumbed to the bursting of its own bubble in 1990 offers a useful, if not quite exact, template for contemporary China, which also features a high-saving/high-investment growth model. Actually, China’s savings and investment shares of GDP are considerably higher than they were in Japan, and China’s household consumption share is much lower at about 40 per cent, plus or minus. I always draw people’s attention to the fact that while China has income per head like Mexico, it has consumption per head that is no higher than that of Peru or numerous countries in sub-Saharan Africa, whatever the ‘wow’ factor might be in Shanghai, Shenzhen and other Tier 1 cities. The pursuit of macroeconomic policies that support industry, restrain wage and salary income and therefore consumption, and suppress the cost of capital leading to misallocation and waste is now as widely recognised in China as it was in Japan.
Chronic over-investment and misallocation of capital both in Japan then and China now are also associated with growing problems in the banking system. In China’s case it is potentially a far bigger problem. Its financial system assets are estimated to amount to about 4 times GDP while in Japan at the peak in 1990, financial system assets were a ‘mere’ 2.5 times GDP. When the property bubble burst in Japan, prices fell sharply. Residential property prices fell by almost 50 per cent between 1990 and the Lehman bust. China will want to avoid antagonising its middle class in this way and may, because it has levers of control, succeed. Nevertheless, we should be clear that the property sector is both much larger than it was in Japan and faces a long period of over-supply and softer demand. From 2018-2021, Chinese home sales were running at about 30–40 per cent more than the sustainable demand is likely to be in the next 10 years, according to demographic and household formation estimates.
Like Japan then (and now), China has a systemic balance-of-payments surplus. Both countries presided over a real estate boom and bust, though in China’s case the tipping point is quite recent and may not manifest itself in quite the same way. Both countries, moreover, had eye-popping economic growth rates which suddenly stopped, exposing high local currency indebtedness. In this at least, China is definitely Japan, rather than other Asia, where the debt crises of the late 1990s took the form of foreign currency—that is US dollar—crises triggered by foreigners wanting to bail out. In Japan in the 1990s and China today, the vast majority of the debt is local currency, owned and owed by domestic residents.
Part of the reason that Japan got into its economic mess and was slow to get out of it, in spite of corporate titans like Sony and Toyota was that it suffered from high levels of institutional rigidity centred around the close interlocking of the vested interests of the ruling Liberal Democratic Party, the state, banks, and corporations—the latter grouped as the so-called ‘Keiretsu’ conglomerates. Again, this is very familiar in China, where the Chinese Communist Party state, the state-owned financial system and state-owned enterprises are similarly intertwined and feature significant conflicts of interest as they function as owners, participants, and regulators subject to laws, of course, but not the rule of law or independent scrutiny and adjudication.
Yet, for all these similarities between Japan and China, there are differences too.
As already suggested, China is unlikely to have a comparable banking crisis because the state-owned financial system will not allow significant banks to fail. The authorities, moreover, can move assets and liabilities around the system, extend and pretend bad loans, and draw out the pain of deleveraging, and shrinkage in real estate.
A closed capital account will also help to insulate China from the risk of significant capital flight, though there is no guarantee that these capital controls will always work.
China is much more pro-active with and keener on economic and financial regulation than Japan was, and this could go some way to help in the management of difficult problems. At the same time though, remember that the penchant for control and for political control, especially, has had and is having a deleterious effect on the trust, confidence and potential of private firms and entrepreneurs, which is liable to have growth-sapping and disruptive consequences.
China is poorer and perhaps less resilient. Like Japan in 1995, China’s current GDP is about 75 per cent of the US, but its income per head is only 18 per cent compared with Japan’s 150 per cent (which is nowadays 56 per cent). This is noteworthy because by way of reflection, China has lower levels of educational attainment, and higher levels of low pay, low skill jobs.
Both countries’ economic tipping points were heralded by rapid ageing, as measured by the peak in the support ratio (of working age adults per retiree), but the effects are more immediate in China at much lower levels of income per head. Cue ‘getting old before you get rich’ debate.
Unlike Japan, China is a geopolitical rival of the US and other liberal-leaning democracies, and faces a hostile external environment, comprising export controls, including most recently on high-end semiconductors on which China is heavily dependent, sanctions, and other commercial restraints.
Finally, and interestingly, until the Japan bubble burst in 1990 and even afterwards, Americans regarded Japan as an innovative, long-term thinking nation that was economically superior and technologically more advanced. Racked by resentment and worry, officials and commentators feared it would go on to overwhelm and overtake their own country.
It didn’t quite work out that way for Japan. Bearing in mind the striking familiarities between the structure and behaviour of 1990s Japan and 2020s China, and even some of the differences, it might not for China either.
This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of the China Foresight Forum, LSE IDEAS, nor The London School of Economics and Political Science.
“File:Great Hall of the People – Beijing” by IQRemix is licensed under CC BY-SA 2.0.
It is somehow strangely difficult for Western economists to understand that it is OK to have a good meal as if served in a monastery, not as ultra fancy expensive as a Las Vegas nightclub. Knowing the Confucian low consumption/high saving lifestyle affecting its economic behaviors and policies, the western economists just could not help denigrating the [low fat vegan economic diet] of Japan and China. They never expend any effort in studying it and working out how best to operate, sustain and improve such a system. Instead, they always wish and pray that both will wake up one day wanting a Vegas type orgy, consumer driven economy, where their own values lie: buy, buy, buy.
This is why household budgeting plans and software tools are only useful in Western economies, where the compulsion to spend is like a tiger wanting to break out the cage, necessitating the smarts of the latest software to contain it. For the average Japanese and Chinese who saves 40% of their take home pay, they only spend what is necessary. So even it is within the budget, it is just not spent because it is not necessary.
Western economists loved to paint the decades of Japanese stagnant economy as a giant failure, almost a laughing stock, while not realizing that the Japanese had been comfortably living in their low consumption lifestyle all along these decades. No big deal… weren’t a fan of Roman orgies anyway.
The question is: Why is there no driving force going the other way to learn from the Confucian lifestyle and economies? Especially in view of the environmentalism in vogue today.