Several economies across the world, most notably in the Eurozone, continue to show only weak signs of recovery from the financial crisis which began in 2008. David M. Kotz argues that developed economies are not merely suffering from the consequences of a financial crash or a severe recession, but from a structural crisis of ‘neoliberal capitalism’. Drawing on ‘social structure of accumulation’ theory, he writes that similar crises have occurred at other points throughout modern history and that the only route to returning to growth is to facilitate the emergence of a new institutional form of capitalism.
What explains the current malaise in developed economies across the world? In my book, The Rise and Fall of Neoliberal Capitalism, I analyse the roots of the economic crisis that began in 2008 and the free-market, or ‘neoliberal’, form of capitalism from which the crisis emerged. I argue that the stubborn stagnation afflicting many of the developed economies cannot be understood simply as the fallout of a severe financial crash or as an unusually severe ‘Great Recession’, but instead is a structural crisis of the neoliberal form of capitalism. This means that the continuing stagnation cannot be resolved by policy measures alone within the constraints of neoliberal capitalism. Rather, a resolution requires major institutional restructuring.
I also address the widespread concern with growing income inequality, a trend that was documented in Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Piketty showed that large shifts in the direction of change in income inequality have occurred at certain points in history in a number of countries. I argue that the main determinant of the trend in income inequality is the institutional form of capitalism, which has changed periodically over time. The ‘regulated capitalism’ that was gradually constructed in the 1930s-40s in the developed countries reduced income inequality through the early 1970s. When that form of capitalism was rapidly replaced by the neoliberal form in the late 1970s to early 1980s in a number of developed countries, the trend in inequality reversed.

Recently a body of mainstream economics literature has appeared on a possible long-run stagnation problem in developed economies. Much of this literature points to such causes as population growth slowdown or absence of major growth-stimulating technological innovations. I argue instead that the cause is found in the breakdown of the institutional form of capitalism that has prevailed since around 1980.
My approach is a modified version of the social structure of accumulation (SSA) theory, which originated in the early 1980s. The SSA theory offers a framework for explaining the alternation between long periods of relatively stable economic growth and long periods of stagnation in capitalist economies. History shows that capitalism has taken a succession of particular institutional forms over time. The SSA theory posits that each institutional form, or SSA, initially promotes profit-making and stable economic expansion. However, eventually an SSA turns from a promoter of stable expansion into an obstacle to it, ushering in a long period of economic stagnation, referred to as a ‘structural crisis’ in this literature. The stagnation persists until a new institutional form of capitalism emerges. Such structural crises have occurred before in the developed capitalist economies, in the last decades of the nineteenth century, the 1930s, and the 1970s. Each was followed by major institutional restructuring, which gave rise to a long period of stable growth.
The book examines the reasons for the unexpected rise and triumph of neoliberal ideas and institutions around 1980. This came as a surprise, given the rejection of free-market ideas and the acceptance of Keynesian economics by the mainstream of the economics establishment after the Great Depression and World War II. I provide documentary evidence that in the course of the 1970s a critical mass of large corporations in the U.S. shifted from their previous informal coalition with organised labour in support of collective bargaining, Keynesian demand management, and a welfare state to promotion of deregulation, privatisation, a union-free environment, and cutbacks in the welfare state.
Focusing on the U.S., I explain the factors that motivated such a dramatic shift. The post-World War II system of regulated capitalism, after bringing some 25 years of rapid economic growth and widely shared prosperity, entered a crisis in the 1970s. A key factor in the 1970s crisis was a long decline in the rate of profit in the U.S. and the leading West European economies, starting in the mid-1960s and lasting until the early 1980s. Big business organisations concluded that falling profits stemmed from rising worker bargaining power in the regulated form of capitalism. They also increasingly chafed at the expanding environmental and other forms of regulation by the state in the 1970s. A decisive part of big business in the U.S., as well as in a number of European countries, found in neoliberalism the means to resolve the problems they had identified.
For several decades, neoliberal capitalism was able to bring a series of long economic expansions punctuated by relatively brief and mild recessions as well as a low rate of inflation. However, the programme of freeing markets and cutting taxes did not lead to a prosperity that trickled down to those in the middle and bottom. Rather than a rising tide that lifted all boats, neoliberal institutions brought stagnating or falling incomes for the majority and a remarkable upward income redistribution to the very rich.
Neoliberal transformation did not unleash the promised wave of investment, which has been sluggish compared to the era of post-war regulated capitalism, but the increasing inequality and rising profits it produced did stimulate initial economic expansion. However, a long economic expansion requires growing demand for output as well as profit incentives for expansion, and stagnating wages and state spending created a problem on the demand side. The demand problem was solved by two other features of neoliberal capitalism, large asset bubbles and a risk-seeking financial sector. Together those two features led to rising debt-fuelled consumer spending, which underpinned the long expansion of the 1990s and that of 2001-07 in the U.S.
However, under the surface the very same features that together promoted long expansions and low inflation — growing inequality, an increasingly risk-seeking financial sector, and a series of large asset bubbles – gave rise to trends that were unsustainable over the long run. In 2007-08 the unsustainable trends — growing household and financial sector debt, the spread of toxic financial assets, and increasing excess capacity in industry – interacted with the deflation of the U.S. real estate bubble to bring a financial panic and Great Recession, which quickly spread in various forms to the other developed countries.
Austerity policies in Europe and the U.S. can be interpreted as an effort to preserve the neoliberal form of capitalism. That form of capitalism has been very favourable for corporate profit and the income of the rich, and it is difficult for its beneficiaries to give it up. Austerity policies also follow logically from the dominant economic ideas of this era, which are difficult to dislodge despite the evidence that austerity only deepens the stagnation.
I argue that both theoretical considerations and historical precedents indicate that the neoliberal form of capitalism can no longer give rise to sustained economic growth. The stagnation will put increasing pressure on all the affected groups in society to find an alternative route to resuming normal economic growth. I suggest that a return to a statist economy is the likely outcome, although that can take different forms, ranging from a right-wing nationalist version to a new round of social democracy or even a shift away from capitalism toward socialism. While the neoliberal form of capitalism is unlikely to survive, which statist form will replace it cannot be predicted in advance and will depend on the outcome of economic and political battles among various groups and classes in the coming years.
The Rise and Fall of Neoliberal Capitalism, published by Harvard University Press, will be released in January 2015
Please read our comments policy before commenting.
Note: This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of EUROPP – European Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics.
Shortened URL for this post: http://bit.ly/1GFPinD
_________________________________
David M. Kotz – University of Massachusetts Amherst
David M. Kotz is Professor of Economics at the University of Massachusetts Amherst and Distinguished Professor in the School of Economics at the Shanghai University of Finance and Economics.
Professor Emeritus Milton Freidman, with all due respect, did not understand the mathematics behind expectations and probability to the extent that neoliberalism could ever be made a viable working model of contemporary economics. Moreover, Professor Emeritus Milton Freidman could not possibly have understood that Glass-Steagall was going to be rendered defunct and scraped with deregulation. Neoliberalism as theorized by Freidman was a poorly thought out model of economics. Neoliberalism today is not classical neoliberalism as envisioned by anyone at the Chicago School of Economics. We have a bastardization of something that may have resembled neoliberalism at one point in time, but it sure as hell is not neoliberalism when it evolves into Casino Capitalism controlled by an oligopoly that collude to rig the system beyond recognition of contemporary economic theory that is presently taught in academic Economics schools. Frankly, neoliberalism is not on the radar screens of the millions upon millions of people worldwide that are not employed due to all of QE Infinity investment going into EM and the 100% overvalued stock market. Nothing trickled down to anyone except the 1%. Totalitarianism is not neoliberalism dressed like a pig with lipstick on, Professor Kotz.
Of course the economic system that we see is not true Neoliberalism. The rich have made inroads into it and distorted it to their own ends. This is entirely predictable.
What started out as an attempt for Neoliberalism gave a lot of power, both economic and political, to the capitalists and they have used these powers to accrue more power. That is what they do.
To expect them to do otherwise is naive. It is just like a true Communist saying that true Communism has never exist because the Dictatorship of the Proletariat did not dissolve itself the way it was supposed to.
People with power never willingly give it up, they seek more.
Since March 10th 2008 around 11:00am Bear Stearns New York City time we have witnessed 29 successive
business quarters of contraction with no end in sight with regard to market improvement. Every single academic Economist in the World failed to realize that housing prices, the price per barrel of oil, et cetera, don’t trend to infinity as a general rule. Equilibrium Economists are unable to restore equilibrium to markets and not a single academic Economist in the entire World has the intellectual capacity to iron out the quantum
economic destruction that has taken place throughout the entire World since Bear Stearns was leveled in the bear raid that forced this issue off onto Economics proper this date. Structurally, the zero sum game has become one of impending doom economically for all nations throughout the World. At the present rate of academic dithering with regard to a Worldwide Global re-set on currencies, and Economics, we are not witnessing progress. Neoliberalism via academia, and the Chicago School of Economics, with specific mention going to Professor Emeritus Milton Freidman, has been rendered defunct. Given that we are forced into a new paradigm of thought in academic Economics, I, for one, support your thesis surrounding a structural analysis of the relevant historiography that has, and will, manifest from here on out. My concern is that academics in Economics don’t realize that there will be no recovery from the contemporary schools of
thought in Economics that brought us collectively to this precipice of World War Three we are all faced with en masse. In brief, I am not advocating for a utopia. I am warning Economics, and Economists, that there is no mathematical solution to the false prophet of Neoliberalism other than to let it die as an unworkable, defunct, and empirically irrational bit of dogma. We have evidenced enough failure of neoliberalism to render it to the dustbin of history, frankly.
NOTE: I have yet to read your book and I was merely commenting on the synopsis of it.
Sincerely, Robert
It was ever thus.In the early Eighties it became apparent to me that the corporate globalists were applying a multi-pronged attack against labour.The unions had become corrupted to a large degree, politicised and irresponsible, but the corporates had plans way beyond bringing the unions to heel.They not only brought most of the union bosses, the ones who mattered, on board, but also the Left, the Academe, the bureaucracy, the mainstream media, the politicians, local government, and public servants generally.Rampant consumerism, the ongoing debasement of currencies and ballooning debt all-round ensured that most people were not taking notice of the hijack perpetrated upon the democratic nation-states.Etc.,etc.It is a learning curve for society insofar as it survives.Democracy in action, whichever way it goes.If the people do not engage the brain and take notice, the inevitable result is a more severe concentration of power with those who are bent on organising and cooperating for their own ends.Once the balance goes towards a power-hungry elite, a new dynamic takes over.This is where we are now.The resolution is unstoppable, but the outcome is unknowable.One thing we know, once the dynamic of natural law takes over, the system is inexorably headed for a breakdown or complete dissolution.