LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

donszelm

June 21st, 2017

Analysing America’s Age of Mass Migration highlights the long-term benefits of immigration

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

donszelm

June 21st, 2017

Analysing America’s Age of Mass Migration highlights the long-term benefits of immigration

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Though a highly emotive issue, the debates surrounding immigration and its impact have focused on the short-term. In assessing the longer-term effects of immigration by considering America’s Age of Mass Migration, however, Sandra Sequeira, Nathan Nunn and Nancy Qian find that the long-run benefits of immigration can be sizeable, and suggest that despite the short-term social costs and tensions of increased immigration, we should consider the long-run benefits of immigration in policy debates.

The debate on the costs and benefits of immigration is currently at the forefront of the policy agenda of many countries. The primary focus is typically on the short-run, immediate effects of immigrants on the communities into which they settle. How will immigrants affect the employment opportunities of natives? How will they affect crime? Far less attention has been paid to the potential long-term effects of immigration.

In our recent study, we examine immigration into the United States during America’s Age of Mass Migration (from 1850–1920) and estimate the causal effect of immigrants on economic and social outcomes approximately 100 years later. Not only was this the period in U.S. history with the highest levels of immigration, but the immigrants that arrived during this time were different from previous waves of immigrants. While earlier immigrants were primarily from Western Europe, subsequent waves also included large numbers of immigrants from Southern, Northern, and Eastern Europe who spoke different languages and had different religious practices.

The main challenge with the analysis is that immigrants had specific reasons to settle in different communities, and these reasons may be associated with the long-run economic and social outcomes of interest. Immigrants may have aimed to settle in areas with the highest growth potential. In this case, we might observe that these areas are growing faster today, but this is not necessarily driven by historical immigration. Alternatively, immigrants may have only managed to settle in areas with poorer growth potential, where land was cheaper and more abundant. The fact that these areas today are growing slower may not be the direct cause of the presence of the immigrants. In both cases, estimates of the effect of immigration could be biased by the inherent characteristics of the places immigrants settled into, which may be important for long-term economic growth, regardless of the extent of immigration.

Our analysis attempts to overcome these issues by exploiting two facts about immigration during this period. The first is that after arriving into the United States, immigrants tended to use the newly constructed railway network to travel inland to their eventual place of residence. Therefore, at any point in time, a county’s connection to the railway affected the number of immigrants that settled in the county. The second fact is that the total inflow of immigrants fluctuated greatly during this period, with the flow of immigrants varying significantly from year-to-year and even decade-to-decade (see Figure 1). In some decades immigration was significantly higher than average (e.g., 1850s, 1880s, and 1900s) and in other decades significantly lower than average (e.g., 1860s, 1870s, and 1890s).

Holding constant the total length of time a county was connected to the railway network, if a county became connected during periods of high immigration, then it will tend to have had more immigrant settlement. Thus, intuitively, our estimates exploit comparisons of counties that became connected at approximately the same point in time (i.e., contiguous decades), but some counties were connected just prior to an immigration boom and others just prior to an immigration lull.

Figure 1. Total number of immigrants arriving in the United States

Our estimates suggest that immigration, measured as the average share of migrants in the population between 1860 and 1920, generated significant economic benefits today.  We find that it resulted in significantly higher incomes, less poverty, less unemployment, more urbanization, and higher educational attainment today. In fact, moving a county with no historical immigration during the age of mass migration to the 50th percentile of the sample (which is a county with a 5% share of immigrants) results in a 20% increase in average per capita income today.

We also find that immigration resulted in an immediate increase in industrialization. Immigrants contributed to the early establishment of more manufacturing facilities and to the development of larger facilities. They also contributed to agricultural productivity in the medium-run and helped create an environment that promoted innovation as measured by patenting rates of both immigrants and native-born. Immigrants also provided an ample supply of unskilled labor, which were crucial for early industrialization. A smaller share of immigrants also brought with them knowledge, experience, and skills that were beneficial for industry and increased productivity in agriculture. Despite evidence of some short-term costs to immigration, as indicated by the rise of nativism and other anti-immigrant movements in the 19th and 20th century, we find no evidence of adverse long-term social effects from immigration. Communities with more historical immigration are not any more likely to have higher crime or lower civic engagement today. While the inflow of immigrants did reduce average educational attainment in the short-run, this effect was reversed in the medium-run as economic wealth created by the immigrants translated into higher educational investment for their children (and for the children of native born Americans in the same locations).

All in all, our findings suggest that the long-run benefits of immigration can be sizeable and that these effects do not appear to come at a social cost.

Extrapolating from these historical results to the current debate on migration requires, however, caution. The Age of Mass Migration occurred during a period of industrial take-off, which was characterized by high demand for labor and vast areas of land available both in the West and in the Midwest. These differences notwithstanding, it is important to also consider some striking similarities. During both migration periods, the pool of immigrants was ethnically diverse and varying in skill level. The short-term social costs and tensions of increased immigration were politically salient in both periods.

These findings highlight the importance of taking a long-run perspective on the current immigration debate. Learning from past episodes of immigration can not only highlight the long-run benefits of immigration but remind us that our policies today will have long-term effects for generations to come.

Immigrants Make America Great” by Paul Sableman is licensed under CC BY 2.0.

This article is based on the paper Migrants and the Making of America: The Short- and Long-Run Effects of Immigration during the Age of Mass Migration.

Please read our comments policy before commenting.

 Note: This article gives the views of the authors, and not the position of USAPP – American Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics.

Shortened URL for this post: http://wp.me/p3I2YF-6QV

________________________________

About the authors

Sandra SequeiraLondon School of Economics
Sandra Sequeira (PhD Harvard, 2009) is an Assistant Professor at the London School of Economics. She is a Research Affiliate with CEPR, a Research Associate with STICERD (EOPP) and Lead Academic for the International Growth Centre (Mozambique). Her research interests include development economics, applied microeconomics and labour economics.

Nathan NunnHarvard University
Nathan Nunn is Frederic E. Abbe Professor of Economics at Harvard University. Professor Nunn was born in Canada, where he received his PhD from the University of Toronto in 2005. Professor Nunn’s primary research interests are in economic history, economic development, cultural economics, political economy and international trade. He is an NBER Faculty Research Fellow, a Research Fellow at BREAD, and a Faculty Associate at Harvard’s Weatherhead Center for International Affairs (WCFIA). He is currently a co-editor of the Journal of Development Economics.

Nancy QianNorthwestern University
Nancy Qian is a professor of Managerial Economics & Decision Sciences. She is a native of Shanghai, China and holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Her research is focused on empirical evidence for a set of core questions in development economics that broadly fall into three sub-categories: demography and development, geography and development and institutions and development.

About the author

donszelm

Posted In: Nancy Qian | Nathan Nunn | Sandra Sequeira | US foreign affairs and the North American neighbourhood

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

LSE Review of Books Visit our sister blog: British Politics and Policy at LSE

RSS Latest LSE Events podcasts

This work by LSE USAPP blog is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 Unported.