LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Dipa Patel

June 17th, 2019

Trump’s threats on Mexican trade and immigration negate the stability dividend of preferential trade deals

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Dipa Patel

June 17th, 2019

Trump’s threats on Mexican trade and immigration negate the stability dividend of preferential trade deals

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Professor Ken Shadlen questions whether the cost of forging complex trade agreements, such as the North American Free Trade Agreement, with the US outweighs the benefits. 

The United States’ last week threatened to apply tariffs on imports from Mexico unless Mexico revamped its approach to Central American migrants passing through the country. This move underscores the power asymmetries in the global economy and undermines the credibility of US trade agreements elsewhere. Essentially, President Trump was threatening to abrogate US commitments under NAFTA (and the World Trade Organization) unless Mexico introduced measures in an area that is not addressed by NAFTA.

These tariffs will not now be applied, and there is debate about just how much Mexico changed its migration policies as a result of Washington’s manoeuvre, the linkage between trade and “non-trade” issues such as immigration does have deep implications for the political economy of international trade, especially within preferential trade agreements such as NAFTA.

The blurred lines between trade and non-trade issues

Many critics of Trump’s threats claim that immigration policy and trade policy are distinct, and that it makes no sense for the administration to link the two. But this misses the point: what is and is not “trade” is determined politically.

Since the 1980s, the United States has conditioned market access on the introduction and enforcement of a wide range of “trade-related” policies, including investment, intellectual property, government procurement practices, and so on. Market size confers to the importing country the power to define what constitutes “trade,” and the definition of “trade” thus has changed according to Washington’s preferences. In that sense, Trump’s trade-immigration linkage manoeuvre is not at all new.

On the one hand, NAFTA is the outcome of massive linkage of this sort, as Mexico was required to introduce extensive changes to policies and practices in a range of trade-related policy areas in order to qualify for the agreement. On the other hand, NAFTA was meant to protect against further “ad-hoc linkage”, whereby new conditions would be attached at the whim of the United States.

Prior to NAFTA, Mexico’s exports largely entered the U.S. market under the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP), which offers preferential market access to exports from developing countries under a wide range of conditions. But GSP preferences can be withdrawn unilaterally, and, being the importing country, the United States changed GSP preferences in response to its changing sentiments. Beneficiary countries always ran the risk of having the US Congress and Executive attach additional conditions to the programme like ornaments on a Christmas tree.

NAFTA and subsequent NAFTA-like trade agreements promised to deliver substantially more predictability and stability than the GSP, but recent events question these premises.

Trump and the NAFTA stability dividend

In 2017-18, Trump warned that Washington would withdraw entirely from NAFTA unless it was renegotiated on terms more to his liking. Last week’s threat to remove preferential market access unless Mexico changed its immigration policies and practices is precisely the sort of behavior that NAFTA was meant to protect against. The agreement supposedly replaced the unstable preferences of GSP, which were always vulnerable to the whims of US politicians, with preferences that were clearly defined, had fixed conditions, and were less prone to being unilaterally withdrawn. Trump’s behaviour shows that this stability dividend has not materialised.

Washington’s actions are something akin to the Mexican government announcing it would stop enforcing the copyrights and patents of US firms unless the United States substantially increased science and technology assistance to help upgrade the stock of biologists, chemists, and engineers in Mexico. The reaction to such an announcement would be ridicule, and Washington would claim that NAFTA (as well as the WTO) binds Mexico to protect intellectual property. The United States would assert, moreover, that its science and technology assistance is not covered by NAFTA; Mexico’s threat would elicit no change of behavior on the part of the US.

Beyond NAFTA per se, these events make one wonder why any country would sign a trade agreement with the United States. After all, if countries already have preferential market access under the GSP, then one of the main benefits of reciprocal trade agreements is to lock-in and stabilise those preferences – even with the need to make substantial concessions on “trade-related” policy areas.

If, in reality, only half of the bargain is locked in and the benefits can evaporate at the whim of the US president, then for many trading partners the benefits of such agreements will be unlikely to compensate for the costs.


Ken Shadlen is Professor of Development Studies in the Department of International Development of the London School of Economics and Political Science. He is currently Head of Department (September 2017-2020). Ken works on the comparative and international political economy of development, with a focus on understanding variation in national policy responses to changing global rules. His recent book Coalitions and Compliance: The Political Economy of Pharmaceutical Patents in Latin America (Oxford University Press, 2018) analyses differences in how countries introduced pharmaceutical patents in the 1990s and then subsequently revised their new pharmaceutical patent systems in the 2000s.

This article was first published on the Latin America and Caribbean Centre Blog.

The views expressed in this post are those of the author and in no way reflect those of the International Development LSE blog or the London School of Economics and Political Science.

About the author

Dipa Patel

Dipa Patel is the Communications and Events Manager for the Department of International Development at LSE. She is also the Managing Editor of the ID at LSE Blog.

Posted In: Featured | Topical and Comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

RSS Justice and Security Research Programme

RSS LSE’s engagement with South Asia

  • Afia Begum, Brick Lane’s ‘Sari Squad’ and South Asian Women’s Rights in the UK
    The 1980s was a period of social and political upheaval — especially in London — when the newly-elected Conservative government led by Margaret Thatcher changed immigration policy to control migration into the United Kingdom. Ayisha Uddin discusses the story of Afia Begum who was deported under the new law after her husband’s death, to showcase the […]
  • Pakistan-India Relations after the 2024 Elections
    Both Pakistan and India held national elections in 2024; their mutual relations are key to regional stability and peace. In this post, Muhammad Ahmad Khan and Saniya Khan discuss how Pakistan views India after the elections, and what options are available to begin to mend their currently strained relations.   During every Vidhan Sabha (State […]