Gujarat has become a centre of caste protests in recent months, as members of the Patidar caste led by Hardik Patel have protested for better access to jobs and education through a quota system. But Maitreesh Ghatak outlines the limitations of the reservation system in India, and argues that without substantial economic reforms and job growth the Patels’ grievances will not be adequately addressed, regardless of whether reservations are introduced.
The Patels in Gujarat rallying for reservation under Hardik Patel’s leadership raises many questions. The first and foremost is: why in Gujarat? Government jobs may well be a big deal in economically backward parts of the country – say, Uttar Pradesh or Bihar. But in terms of the growth rate of per capita income, Gujarat has been among the very top of Indian states in the last decade and a half, earning Narendra Modi the title of Vikas Purush and generating nation-wide buzz about the Gujarat model.
Now it is true that some of the social and human development indices in Gujarat are not in line with its rank in terms of the level and growth rate of average incomes as noted in the 2013 report of the Raghuram Rajan committee. Still, Gujarat is indeed top ranked among Indian states in terms of ease of doing business or economic freedom, justifying its image of a business-friendly state.
What the Patel agitation underscores is the fact that economic growth in Gujarat did not translate into sufficient employment growth. Between 2004-05 and 2009-10, for example, while the country overall experienced a small growth in total employment, Gujarat experienced a net decline, according to the NSSO. A major driver behind Gujarat’s impressive industrial growth is the expansion of capital-intensive sectors (e.g., petroleum refining), which do not fuel job growth in the same way as more labour-intensive sectors. Resentment against reservation of seats for socially under-privileged groups in Gujarat is an outgrowth of this phenomenon of jobless growth.
However, introducing reservation for the Patels – or any other group for that matter – will hardly solve their problem of unemployment. Given the size of the Indian economy, the reach of the reservation system is fairly limited. The number of government jobs that become available every year is around a meagre 1% of the total number of registered educated unemployed in the country. Just a few weeks ago, 368 job openings for peons in UP resulted in 23 lakh applications, of which 1.5 lakhs were from college graduates, some of them engineers and PhDs. Also, merely 20% of India’s total population in the 18+age bracket is enrolled in some higher education institution, private or public. The overall impact of reservations on average educational and economic outcomes is thus bound to be limited to a relatively small segment of the population.
Those who drafted our reservation policies were aware of this. For them, reservation was a necessary step to strengthen the representation of disadvantaged groups in the arena of administrative power. This, they hoped, would make the state machinery more sensitive to the needs of these groups and they, in turn, would feel empowered through a sense of participation in the governance of the country. So, the main objectives of reservation policies in India are the social and political uplift of the average member of backward castes (SCs, STs, and OBCs, who together constitute approximately two-thirds of the total population). Of course, it was expected that some of these benefits would trickle down in the form of economic progress of these groups as well.
All studies show that the backward castes are significantly behind the higher castes in terms of education, employment, and economic status. However, one could argue that is because they have been historically poor, and social backwardness is really a reflection of economic backwardness. After all, there is poverty among forward castes too. Which is why many, including Hardik Patel, argue that reservation should be economic class-based, not caste-based.
The problem with this argument is that it denies social discrimination completely. Two individuals of similar economic status do not always have the same access to opportunities in a society where caste prejudice runs deep.
Everyday there are news stories about Dalits facing various forms of social discrimination. For example, a 12-year-old Dalit boy in Jodhpur was recently beaten up by a teacher for touching a plate meant for upper castes during the mid-day meal at his school, causing dozens of other Dalit students from his village to stay away from school in fear. Leaving aside grim news items, research on intergenerational mobility shows that if two generations are compared in terms of education, employment and prosperity (e.g., if the father is less educated what is the probability that the child will be highly educated), economic mobility within the higher castes has historically been much greater than within the lower castes. So saying “why not reservations on economic criteria only” denies the reality of caste-based discrimination and the fact that social identities – and not just economic factors – govern the prospect of upward mobility.
At the same time, some inherent limitations of the reservation policy cannot be overlooked. There is an innate tension between the long-term goal of removing caste-based discrimination, and perpetuating a policy based on caste itself. In implementing this policy, the eligibility criteria for disadvantaged castes are often set lower than those for the general category, which perpetuates the ‘backward’ tag of these groups. It also creates resentment among those who are economically backward among the forward castes, since it is hard to quantify and compare the disadvantages created by social and economic handicaps. Sensible adjustments can be made to balance between these two types of handicap, which often but not always go together. One would be to limit the benefits of reservation to one or two generations of the same family. Another would be to give priority to the economically backward members of socially backward groups.
It has to be admitted that the overall effectiveness of the policy of reservations has been limited. The representation of the backward castes in top administrative posts remains as low as 23% in 2011 – after many decades of reservation – though they constitute two-thirds of the whole population. Some could argue this means the percentage of reservation should be increased even further. But in the case of education and jobs, it is often difficult to find enough eligible candidates from these groups, and more often than not the reserved seats lie vacant.
The studies on inter-generational mobility mentioned earlier reveal one silver lining though. It appears that in the last two decades, economic mobility within the lower castes has improved considerably, and is now comparable with mobility within the upper castes. The likely reason for this is the expansion of opportunities in the private sector, both educational and job-related, as a result of economic reforms. After all, since the early 80s, total employment has not changed much in the public sector, but has gone up by more than 60% in the organized private sector. Hence, politically empowering the backward castes through reservations, and increasing their economic mobility through economic reforms and job-creation can actually complement each other.
Without substantial economic reforms, and job growth some of the old fault lines in the country’s social and economic terrain are bound to open up. The movement against reservations in Gujarat is a symptom of this.
This article originally appeared October 11 on NDTV.com. It is reposted with the author’s permission.
Cover image credit: flickr/Jonathan Gross CC BY-ND 2.0
Note: This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of the South Asia @ LSE blog, nor of the London School of Economics. Please read our comments policy before posting.
About the Author
Maitreesh Ghatak is Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics. Maitreesh is a regular contributor to the South Asia @ LSE blog. View previous posts here.
I doubt the conclusion of the author. He seems to be sitting too far away from ground realities in India. The Reservation policy has substantially benefited all those categories for whom it was intended. And this for more than one generation. But the more aggressive and the better off among the so-called Backward and Other Backward classes ( Yadavs for example) have taken away the lion’s share of the benefit. The really underprivileged, namely SC, ST and the extremely poor, have lost out. The benefited powerful categories have also become politically organized and powerful. Witness the brazenness of Lalu Yadav, a convicted criminal parading the election grounds in Bihar! From this stand point “economic reforms” a hobby horse of economists and business men, are unlikely to bring solace to the really deserving. Rural education, rural projects, and more investment in agriculture, irrigation and the like will work better.
Coming to the Patels of Gujarat the story is very different. Firstly Hardik and his cohorts are really aiming to abolish reservation because their employment is being thwarted by the lower classes ( not the bottom most SC/ST etc) under the reservation umbrella. Secondly, the type of jobs to which these Patels would be attracted is not growing fast enough to match the population growth among Patels and similar categories. Agricultural incomes are not growing fast enough to
The basic issue which the political parties dread to face, examine and accept is this: Reservation for whole classes and categories, as units, has totally outgrown its utility. Affirmative policies, however must continue but hey be targeted to individual families irrespective of classes and categories, the deciding factor of eligibility being poverty and material deprivation including absence of employable education and not any badge of class or category. The present BCs and OBCs will oppose this tooth and nail but they must be overcome if Reservation benefit must really reach the most deserving.
R.Venkatanarayanan
The caste system is very much entrenched in Indian society. The ‘reservation’ and ‘quota’ has made a dent because it has been around for a long time. Elements who want to do away with the quota system. One way is for every caste to demand reservation and force the government to abandon the concession. The Brahmins want a quota! The Hardik protest seems to be part of this plot. Is it a coincidence that Hardik is tolerated and even protected? For example Hardik has exhorted his followers to kill some cops instead of committing suicide. Encouraging suicide is illegal and of course killing anyone is illegal. Yet the government of India is not taking note.
One may justifiably surmise that the ‘beef’ issue is just to disempower the meat industry sector dominated by a certain community. The truth behind Maggie Noodle soupy predicament is unclear. But Ramdev Baba food products are being actively promoted. NGOs highlighting the plight of the underprivileged are being hounded. Where will this “Indian Spring” (or reverse Spring) lead to?