LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Blog Admin

January 18th, 2018

How the design of housing vouchers can help those on low incomes to live in neighborhoods they prefer.

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Blog Admin

January 18th, 2018

How the design of housing vouchers can help those on low incomes to live in neighborhoods they prefer.

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

For many in the US, the rent is still too high – more than a quarter of US renters pay more than half of their income on housing, and ten percent of this group receives government housing subsidies. In new research, Judy Geyer examines how housing vouchers influence where people choose to live. She finds that when the maximum allowable voucher amount can vary by neighborhood, rather than being capped for an entire city or town, then recipients are more likely to choose to live in neighborhoods with lower crime rates and better schools. 

US Housing price rises, particularly in urban areas, are increasingly a financial burden on many households. In 2015, 37 percent of US households rented their home. That same year, the typical renter household had an annual income of $37,900 and more than 26 percent of renters paid more than 50 percent of their income in rent.  Roughly 10 percent of these renters receive rental housing subsidies from the government.

Rental housing subsidies can greatly improve the financial wellbeing of low-income households. Housing subsidies also affect where you live. Where people are able to live is important to study because the quality of your neighborhood affects your physical health, mental health, happiness, and well-being. Low-income households are especially vulnerable to stress and depression.

In our research, we find that how the government supports low-income households matters. By providing housing vouchers which have caps that can vary by neighborhood rather than by city or town, policy makers can be far more effective at moving those who receive them to better neighborhoods, and at a much lower cost than some alternatives.

Place-based subsidies means the government decides

When might it make sense for the government to entice low-income households to live in a particular location? When governments spend public funds to build units designed for low-income households, they are encouraging those households to live in a particular place. Over the last century, most US subsidized housing policy focused on “place-based” subsidies, which were aimed at increasing the supply of affordable units in particular areas of towns and cities. Currently, the majority of US renters who benefit from housing subsidies live in rental units specifically built or designated as subsidized units.

Place-based subsidies mean that the money is tied to a specific location, not the tenant. If the subsidized tenant wishes to live on a different street, a different neighborhood, or different city, they would lose their housing subsidy unless they found another available, subsidized unit. Long waitlists for subsidized units make it very difficult to switch units. So, why are place-based subsidies so popular? They certainly help provide special-needs housing for low-income individuals with disabilities, who would have little to no good options in the private housing market. Place-based subsidies also create affordable housing in areas where there would certainly be none, such as in midtown Manhattan.

If the government correctly guesses where the “good” neighborhoods are, then it can identify good places on which to tack on housing subsidies. However, governments are not always good at evaluating a neighborhood’s potential. Many urban public housing structures built in the mid-1900s ended up as epicenters of highly segregated neighborhoods with high crime rates. Instead of the government acting as a real estate developer, the Low-Income Housing Tax Credit program places the responsibility of choosing “good neighborhoods” on private real estate developers who have a stake in the outcome. Private real estate developers might do a better job at selecting “good” places. Still, all place-based subsidies are long-term investments. It is very difficult for policy makers to control the long-term quality of a neighborhood.

Housing vouchers mean renters have a choice

An alternative to place-based subsidies is tenant-based subsidies. The US Housing Choice Voucher program, serves roughly 2.2 million people in the US. In this program, the subsidy follows the person rather than a home. The advantage of a tenant-based housing subsidy is that households have a lot more flexibility to choose a location. If the location turns out to be a poor choice, the household can move and take their voucher with them. This subsidy design frees policy makers from choosing which neighborhoods are “good” for the subsidy recipient.

Do households with vouchers choose to live in different neighborhoods than households who have place-based subsidies? Just as we would expect, households with vouchers tend to live in slightly better neighborhoods than households who live in public housing, in terms of lower crime rates and better schools. However, on average they tend to live in neighborhoods that are slightly worse than those of average low-income households (most of whom do not receive subsidies).

Photo by Derek Liang on Unsplash

As all home buyers and renters know, there is a tradeoff between neighborhood quality and housing unit size/quality. Housing prices vary by neighborhood. The same budget might afford a grand apartment in a bad neighborhood, or a small and un-renovated apartment in a great neighborhood.  By not moving to much better neighborhoods, voucher recipients are using most of the value of their voucher on housing size and quality in “mediocre” neighborhoods, rather than more modest apartments in better neighborhoods.

Why not move to a much better neighborhood? There are many reasons. Voucher recipients might prefer to stay in neighborhoods close to their friends, family, or social network who also have low incomes. Or, they may not have the time and resources to explore new neighborhoods that are farther away from their original neighborhood. Or, they might experience and/or fear housing discrimination. While housing discrimination by race and ethnicity it is not legal in the US, it is legal to discriminate based on means of payment.

Specific design features of housing vouchers affect renters’ choice 

Regardless of elements that may deter a voucher recipient from considering far better neighborhoods, our research shows that the design of the housing choice voucher can affect neighborhood choice. How can policy makers compare different designs of the voucher program rules? One method is to use experiments to study outcomes of alternative policies. However, experiments are expensive, and it can take a long time to track household outcomes. To compare many different policy designs or even just to figure out what kinds of experiments to run, it can be helpful to build simulation models.

By first studying the location decisions of voucher households in the City of Pittsburgh, our research contrasts the likely housing and neighborhood choice of voucher households under a broad range of possible voucher policies. In particular, we find that voucher recipients will choose to live in better neighborhoods if the maximum allowable voucher amount can vary by neighborhood, for example by census tracts or postal code.  Currently, caps on voucher amount are fixed across a city or town, rather than varying by neighborhood.  Although such a change in the maximum allowable voucher amount would increase program costs, compared to a program that imply increases the maximum allowable voucher amount by 20 percent, it would be twice as effective at moving voucher recipients to better neighborhoods and it would be only one third the cost.

While politicians debate the merits of supply-side subsidies versus demand-side subsidies, policy researchers continue to look for evidence of promising voucher policy design. With millions of households paying more than 50 percent of their income to rent their home, cost-efficient policy options to alleviate housing burdens and to facilitate access to quality neighborhoods will continue to be one of the hot research topics in US policy debates.

Please read our comments policy before commenting.            

Note:  This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of USAPP– American Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics.

Shortened URL for this post: http://bit.ly/2mVVDsj

 _________________________________ 

About the author

Judy GeyerAbt Associates Inc
Dr. Geyer is an economist at Abt Associates Inc., a public policy consulting firm in Cambridge, MA, and has taught courses at Tufts University and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Her research focuses primarily on household economic behavior, especially as affected by a range of programs including insurance, subsidies, and reward programs.  She holds a PhD in economics from Carnegie Mellon University.

About the author

Blog Admin

Posted In: Judy Geyer | Urban, rural and regional policies

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

LSE Review of Books Visit our sister blog: British Politics and Policy at LSE

RSS Latest LSE Events podcasts