LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Blog Admin

September 9th, 2015

Governments of resource-rich states lower income taxes and restrict public expenditure in response to revenue shocks.

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Blog Admin

September 9th, 2015

Governments of resource-rich states lower income taxes and restrict public expenditure in response to revenue shocks.

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Alex James 80x108Two of the most resource-rich states in the US, Wyoming and Alaska, lack an income tax and also spend more per resident than any other. In new research, Alex James examines whether low tax rates and high spending are linked to states having large amounts of natural resources. He finds that when resource prices rise, state governments lower tax rates but do not tend to increase public expenditure, and that they decrease public expenditures when resource prices fall.

Of the seven U.S. states that currently do not have an individual income tax, three (Wyoming, Alaska and Texas) are resource rich. Surprisingly, in 2008 state government spending per resident was greater in Wyoming and Alaska than in any other state. In fact, per resident, spending in Alaska was greater than that in California and Massachusetts, combined. Are low tax rates and high spending rates a result of natural-resource endowments? The answer to this question has important policy implications and is particularly relevant to both the development literature and the ongoing debate over the so-called “tax-expenditure nexus”.

Milton Friedman famously argued that the only way to shrink the size of government is to “starve the beast” by decreasing tax revenue. Specifically, he argued that:

Government will spend whatever the tax system will raise plus a good deal more. Every step we take to strengthen the tax system, whether by getting people to accept payroll taxes they otherwise would not accept, or by cooperating in enacting higher income taxes and excise taxes or whatnot, fosters a higher level of government spending.

While others have echoed this argument, testing its efficacy has proven difficult given the simultaneous nature of the problem. Does increased government spending require governments to tax more or does increased government revenue allow governments to spend more? Exploiting independent revenue shocks generated by large resource price swings offers a unique opportunity to shed light on this intriguing question.

The baseline estimation procedure uses a panel of U.S. state data, including the continental U.S. states from 1958 to 2008. The estimation relies on variation within states, not across ones. This is important, as there are clearly many important differences between the states of, for example, Wyoming and New Hampshire – only one of which being that Wyoming is rich with hydrocarbons and New Hampshire is not.

The main explanatory variable is resource-revenue – revenue generated from a severance tax, rents and royalties – expressed relative to state GDP. The extraction of natural resources may depend on state-specific environmental policies, tax rates and leasing agreements. This is problematic as a state government may, for example, incentivize additional oil drilling in an effort to finance additional expenditures. In this case, it would not be the additional revenue that caused additional government expenditures, but rather a third and unobserved variable that caused both resource-based revenue and expenditures to rise. In light of this, endowments of oil and gas – defined as the volume of oil and gas deposits (estimated in 1999) interacted with annual energy prices – is used to proxy for resource-based government revenue. This way, within state (but across time) variation in resource-based revenue is defined by variation in energy prices, which are determined by international factors, and are largely unbiased by state-specific outcomes.

Oil jack in Texas Credit: Paul Lowry (Flickr, CC-BY-2.0)
Oil jack in Texas Credit: Paul Lowry (Flickr, CC-BY-2.0)

The baseline analysis consists of examining the (within state) correlation between resource-based revenue (approximated for using oil and gas endowments) and a variety of state fiscal outcomes. My results suggest that state governments respond rather conservatively to revenue shocks. For example, in response to a rise in resource prices, governments typically transfer about 25 percent of additional revenue back to constituents in the form of lower, non-resource tax rates. In particular, there is strong evidence that income tax rates (especially for high income earners) are reduced in response to a positive revenue shock. Surprisingly, there is little evidence that positive revenue shocks increase public expenditures but some evidence that governments decrease spending in response to negative revenue shocks.

Aside from the specific point estimates there are more general conclusions that should be considered. First, do governments “spend whatever the tax system will raise” as Friedman famously claimed? The answer turns out to be “perhaps not”. Further, natural resources, long believed to “curse” economic growth (see for example Jeffery Sach’s and Andrew Warner’s seminal work), may positively affect growth by reducing distortionary taxes, like the income tax.

It’s also important to understand that the state government of Wyoming, for example, did not eliminate income tax revenue from its budget. Rather, it substituted for it by taxing the extraction of hydrocarbons. Governments of neighboring states that were not blessed with such rich natural resources, such as that of Nebraska, are not well positioned to emulate the fiscal structure of a state like Wyoming (as the Governor of Nebraska, Dave Heineman recently proposed to do)—and they shouldn’t try.

Finally, a surprising feature of this research is the observed disconnect between the stated political preferences of the residents of resource-rich states and reality. Alaska, Texas and North Dakota are often considered to be three of the most “free” or “libertarian” states in the Union (see for example Freedom In the 50 States) and opinion surveys echo this result. However, such indices usually ignore the tax burden placed on the energy sector (and in my experience from living in Alaska and Wyoming, constituents do as well). A more comprehensive measure of government size, perhaps one that considers the role of public spending – or at least the tax revenue generated from the energy sector – would make Alaska and Wyoming look more like Sweden than the libertarian meccas they claim to be. This raises the interesting prospect that political preferences ultimately depend on (among other things) natural-resource endowments that relieve constituents of the burden of taxes while simultaneously shielding them from the hardships that usually accompany the insufficient provision of public goods.

This article is based on the paper ‘US State Fiscal Policy and Natural Resources’, in the American Economic Journal: Economic Policy.

Please read our comments policy before commenting. 

Note:  This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of USApp– American Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics.  

Shortened URL for this post:  http://bit.ly/1L1biNe

______________________

About the author

Alex James 80x108Alexander JamesUniversity of Alaska, Anchorage
Alexander James is an Assistant Professor of Economics at the University of Alaska, Anchorage. After receiving his Ph.D in economics from the University of Wyoming, he spent two years as a research fellow at the Center for the Analysis of Resource Rich Economies. His research interests are broad, including a variety of topics related to natural resources, the environment, economic development and public policy.

About the author

Blog Admin

Posted In: Alex James | Urban, rural and regional policies

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

LSE Review of Books Visit our sister blog: British Politics and Policy at LSE

RSS Latest LSE Events podcasts

This work by LSE USAPP blog is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 Unported.