LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Blog Admin

June 4th, 2014

The Fed must explicitly react to movements on the stock market if it values stability and wishes to avoid large consumption and output swings

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Blog Admin

June 4th, 2014

The Fed must explicitly react to movements on the stock market if it values stability and wishes to avoid large consumption and output swings

0 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Eddie Gerba 80x108Over the past few years, the Fed has been blamed for fuelling the post-2001 financial market boom by maintaining record-low interest rates and ignoring the developments on the stock market. But, should central bankers really care about stock market swings when there is so much uncertainty and noise involved? Eddie Gerba returns to this pre-crisis debate and re-examines the ‘consensus’ that monetary policy, by responding heavily to movements in inflation and output, is enough to bring the markets under control and stabilize the economy. Using a macro-financial model, he finds that an economy is better off overall in terms of consumption gains when a policy that explicitly targets stock market developments is adopted.

In the Financial Stability Report of November 2012, Bank of England observed that the price to book ratio, or ‘asset price wedge’ (the market value and the book value of capital) of bank equity was down to its historical lowest at 0.5. They noted that the sharp fall in the ratio over the past two years has been the result of two problems: investors question the value of net assets reported in the accounts, but more crucially, seriously doubting as to whether the banks will be able to generate earnings sufficient to exceed the required return of investors following a 10 percent fall in market expectations of profits over the next three years.

Moreover, pessimistic market sentiment has not only been isolated to the banking sector. Corporate markets on both sides of the Atlantic have equally been affected. Following a persistent boom in the US stock market of 87 percent between 2002:Q2 and 2007:Q2, in just two years (between 2007:Q2 and 2009:Q3) the value of S&P500 had fallen by 40 percent. One of the key reasons behind the boom had been the prospect of higher productivity growth of US firms, allowing firm earnings to persistently increase between 2002 and 2007. This consolidation in firm finances resulted in two things. First, it brought the default probability on loans down to negligible levels, leading to an easing in firm borrowing conditions. Second, the investors’ required earnings sharply declined since they believed that firms would have enough financial capital to continue growing.

On the downside in 2008, the default risk increased, pushing investors’ required earnings sharply up. To illustrate the boom-bust cycle, net corporate dividends (a good rough measure for firm net earnings) more than doubled from less than 400 to more than 800 billion USD during the boom period. Conversely, during the latest recession the value of net dividends fell by 38 percent. The deteriorating stock market value combined with the greatly weakened cash-flows of firms has resulted in a fall in the real private investment of more than one-third, or 800 billion dollars between 2007:Q2 and 2009:Q3.

I incorporated these observations into a theoretical model of the economy with a financial sector and a borrowing constraint for firms. In particular, I introduces an explicit stock-market mechanism where the stock prices have a fundamental and a non-fundamental component. Moreover, firms’ decisions to produce and invest are dependent on the stock market price, as is the level of access to external credit. Introducing these aspects in a standard macroeconomic model significantly altered its dynamics. Figure 1 depicts the impulse responses following an improvement in firm productivity. The dotted lines represent the responses in a standard macroeconomic model while the full lines are the impulse responses of the current model. 

Figure 1 – Impulse responses to a positive 1 percent productivity shock

Gerba Fig 1

Note: The dotted lines are the responses in the standard macroeconomic model, and the full lines in the extended model. The responses are expressed in percentage points. Horizontal axis gives number of quarters since the shock.

Compared to a standard model, the economy is up to three times more volatile when an explicit stock market mechanism is introduced. Investment rises by 1 percent (instead of 0.25 percent), firm net worth by 0.6 percent (instead of 0.2 percent), the accumulation of capital increases by 0.08 percent (instead of 0.05 percent) and output expands by 0.27 percent (instead of 0.1 percent). Moreover, following a 1 percent increase in the non-fundamental component of the stock market price (Figure 2), the economy expands for the first 3 quarters, but then enters a contraction and does not recover from it until 3 years after. This boom-bust dynamics is similar to the one experienced more recently in the US.

Figure 2 – Impulse responses to a positive 1 percent shock to the non-fundamental component of the stock market price.

Gerba Fig 2

Note: The responses are expressed in percentage points. Horizontal axis gives number of quarters since the shock.

I then used this framework to evaluate which policy is optimal in terms of minimizing the consumption losses (or symmetrically, maximizing the consumption gains) of consumers in the model. Both individually and together, I evaluated monetary policy that targeted inflation, output and stock market prices. I then compared these in economic scenarios that included and excluded a stock market bubble as well as one where the probability of a stock market bubble was 50 percent but central bankers had incomplete knowledge regarding the current state of the economy.

Experiments show that consumers are, on average 10 percent better off in terms of foregone consumption with a monetary policy that explicitly targets stock market prices compared to a policy that only targets inflation and output. The superiority of this policy is maintained even when we take into consideration that central bankers might hold incomplete information regarding the true state of the asset price wedge – the difference between the market value and the book value of capital. These results can be interpreted as overturning those of the ‘consensus’ since in order for the standard policy (inflation and output only) rule to be preferred, the probability of an economy without a wedge has to be higher than the probability of a wedge, which is not a reasonable assumption.

This article is based on the paper Reconnecting investment to stock markets: the role of corporate net worth evaluation which has been is submitted to the Journal of Monetary Economics.

Featured image credit: Credit: Richard Cawood (Creative Commons BY NC)

Please read our comments policy before commenting.

Note:  This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of USApp– American Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics. 

Shortened URL for this post:  http://bit.ly/1ne4b6u

 _________________________________

About the author

Eddie Gerba 80x108Eddie Gerba – LSE European Institute
Eddie Gerba is a Research Fellow at the London School of Economics and holds degrees from Pompeu Fabra, ETH Zurich, LSE, and University of Kent. Eddie’s research interests lie in the fields of macroeconomics and quantitative finance. Of particular interest to his research are financial frictions, liquidity cycles, monetary policy, financial intermediation theory, as well as risk management and macroeconomic stability. Method-wise, his interests and experience lie in DSGE-models, computational methods, time-series econometrics, and derivative pricing models.

 

About the author

Blog Admin

Posted In: Economy | Eddie Gerba | LSE Comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

LSE Review of Books Visit our sister blog: British Politics and Policy at LSE

RSS Latest LSE Events podcasts