In an interview with EUROPP’s editor Stuart Brown and British Politics and Policy at LSE’s editor Joel Suss, Thomas Piketty discusses the rise in income and wealth inequality outlined in his book, Capital in the Twenty-First Century, and what policies should be adopted to prevent us returning to the kind of extreme levels of inequality experienced in Europe prior to the First World War. Professor Piketty recently gave a lecture at the LSE, the video of which can be seen online here.
Your research shows that inequality is rising and that without government action this trend is likely to continue. However, are we correct to assume that inequality is a fundamentally negative development in terms of its consequences on society?
There is no problem with inequality per se. In actual fact, up to a point inequality is fine and perhaps even useful with respect to innovation and growth. The problem is when inequality becomes so extreme that it no longer becomes useful for growth. When inequality reaches a certain point it often leads to the perpetuation of inequality over time across generations, as well as to a lack of mobility within society. Moreover, extreme inequality can be problematic for democratic institutions because it has the potential to lead to extremely unequal access to political power and the ability for citizens to make their voice heard.
There is no mathematical formula that tells you the point at which inequality becomes excessive. All we have is historical experience, and all I have tried to do through my research is to put together a large body of historical experience from over twenty countries across two centuries. We can only take imperfect lessons from this work, but it’s the best that we have. One lesson, for instance, is that the kind of extreme concentration of wealth that we experienced in most European countries up until World War One was excessive in the sense that it was not useful for growth, and probably even reduced growth and mobility overall.
This situation was destroyed by World War One, the Great Depression, and World War Two, as well as by the welfare state and progressive taxation policies which came after these shocks. As a consequence, wealth concentration was much lower in the 1950s and 1960s than it was in 1910, but this did not prevent growth from happening. If anything, this probably contributed to the inclusion of new social groups into the economic process and therefore to higher growth. So one important historical lesson from the 20th century is that we don’t need 19th century-style inequality to generate growth in the 21st century, and we therefore don’t want to return to that level of inequality in Europe.
How would you respond to those who doubt whether there is sufficient evidence to draw this kind of conclusion?
This will always be an imperfect inference because we are in the social sciences and we should not have any illusions about what is possible. We can’t run a controlled experiment across the 20th century or replay the century as if World War One and progressive taxation never occurred. All we have is our common historical experience, but I think this is enough to reach a number of fairly strong conclusions.
The lesson we have already mentioned – that we don’t need the kind of extreme inequality of the 19th century in order to have economic growth – is simply one imperfect lesson, but there are other important lessons if you look at, for instance, the rise of inequality in the United States over the past 30 years. For example, is it useful to pay managers a ten million dollar salary rather than only one million dollars? You really don’t see this in the data: the extra performance and job creation in companies which pay managers ten million dollars rather than one. In the United States over the past 30 years almost 75 per cent of the aggregate primary income growth has gone to the top of the distribution. Given the relatively mediocre productivity performance and the per capita GDP growth rate of 1.5 per cent per year, having nearly three quarters of that going to the top isn’t a very good deal for the rest of the population.
This will always be a complicated and passionate debate. Social science research is not going to transform the political conflict over the issue of inequality with some kind of mathematical certainty, but at least we can have a more informed debate using this historical cross-country evidence. Ultimately that is all my research is aiming to do.
What specific policies can be used to prevent us returning to the kind of extreme levels of inequality you have discussed?
There are a large number of policies which can be used in combination to regulate inequality. Historically the main mechanism to reduce inequality has been the diffusion of knowledge, skills and education. This is the most powerful force to reduce inequality between countries: and this is what we have today, with emerging countries catching up in terms of productivity levels with richer countries. Sometimes this can also work within countries if we have sufficiently inclusive educational and social institutions which allow large segments of the population to access the right skills and the right jobs.
However while education is tremendously important, sometimes it’s not sufficient in isolation. In order to prevent the top income groups and top wealth groups from effectively seceding from the rest of the distribution and growing much faster than the rest of society, you also need progressive taxation of income and progressive taxation of wealth – both inherited and annual wealth. Otherwise there is no natural mechanism to prevent the kind of extreme concentration of income and wealth that we’ve seen in the past from happening again.
Most of all, what we need is financial transparency. We need to monitor the dynamics of all of the different income and wealth groups more effectively so that we can adapt our policies and tax rates in line with whatever we observe. The lack of transparency is actually the biggest threat – we may end up one day in a much more unequal society than we thought we were.
Note: This article gives the views of the interviewee, and not the position of the British Politics and Policy blog, nor of the London School of Economics. Please read our comments policy before posting. Featured image credit: Harvard Press
Thomas Piketty – Paris School of Economics
Thomas Piketty is a Professor of Economics at the Paris School of Economics. He is the author of Capital in the 21st Century (Harvard University Press, March 2014).
I congratulate piketty for raising global debate on in equality though his statistical analysis of near about global data even it’s authenticity is doubtful. His effort is bold.I may disagree with many of his assumptions in his book capital like many of the basic conceptual distortionary definitions of of Keynes as against the basic ideas of classical economic analysts like Adamsmith,Recardo,more elaborated by marx after discarding his certain faultily deduced political ideas and so also the premises for the conclusions.
The man is a social and political animal is a self evident truth.He is person actuated by natural instincts and controlled by social laws of the society in which he lives. Economics is an element like politics of a social being. Both economics and politics often run in oposite directions up to cetain point and gets reset in many social revolutions through change of governments and even state/nations as we see from historical evidences.
Adamsmith is considered as the person who laid the foundations in the form of basic ideas as the basic premises of economic analysis as a scientific study for some predictive nature of future accumulation of national wealth and wellbeing of the commonwealth.the said ideas were critically put to test with emirical data and improved by Recardo and Karl Marx.
One important element of uncertainty of data not tallying with the original conclusions of Adamsmith or even Marx was political decionmaking of new sovereign nation states that were existing or have sprung during interrugnum of Adamsmith and ww1And later periods.therfore there is some new variables apart from the variables taken by classical it’s I. E value, labor time for measuring the value,price,Money and various components of said broad variables and division of labor as social categories of economic process undertaken by indidual or corporate entrepreneur in his quest for profit maximisation and this was in the context of dominant national marketseconomies where for
eign trade and their technology was as subordinate.
Piketty capital ignored the both Adam and Marx and ignored the role of markets with boundaries and without boundaries as a field of free compititon as against crony çomprtition under the controlling state machinery.
This can be academically studied like in the context many hither to either autocratic or nationalis tic empire without borders and growth equality and inequality in the context of frè flow of trade and compititon or walled disunited or fragmented markets and states.
Their is an inherent element of inequality arising out of transfer of values and price benefits in the money terms in favour entities and countried who employ modern methods of productions and supply lines involving having greater productivity than the global average provided global free competition under like WTO regime and further distorted by aggravated by sovereign states individually and also in some forms of hidden or open cartels.
The book has not touched these underlying causes of growing global as well as national inequalities and the political discontents arising out of the economic phenomena.
It goes without saying that the remedy you suggest that the progressive global tax is unrealistic unless it also remedy the underlying free markets distorting sovereign states is substituted by global democratic government as against the hither to nationalic empires.
As soul satisfying as this discussion is, It relies on faulty analysis to reach a desired social conclusion. A country is not a single business or even a single sector. It is a combination of sectors, each with a different set of income distributions, some looking like the traditional bell curve, some with asymmetric distributions — each with a different median and thus with different margins for the deciles and quintiles.
And finally within each sector different sets of risk profiles, requiring different returns.
Analysis should proceed from the bottom up, the movement within and across each of the boundaries.
Regretfully it would appear that Mr. Piketty is taking his audience for scientific fools. I do imagine that he is satisfied with the income inequality among members of the economic profession.