LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

Blog Admin

February 17th, 2018

The European Parliament is more representative of European citizens than we give it credit for

0 comments | 1 shares

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Blog Admin

February 17th, 2018

The European Parliament is more representative of European citizens than we give it credit for

0 comments | 1 shares

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Does the European Parliament adequately represent the views of European citizens? Drawing on a recent study, Miriam Sorace finds that it is far more representative of voters’ views than commonly thought. It is the lack of information about European election campaigns, as well as a tendency for voters to cast protest votes that can lead to less effective representation.

Critiques of EU democracy are frequent, and are by no means only the prerogative of extreme nationalists. Yanis Varoufakis has called the EU a ‘democracy-free zone’ while Nigel Farage believes the Members of the European Parliament (MEPs) are ‘anti-democratic zealots’. These are only two provocative examples of the widely-held Eurosceptic perception that the European Parliament is useless and that the EU embodies a serious democratic deficit.

Concrete evidence, however, paints a less apocalyptic picture, one in which the European Parliament is attentive to and does represent European voters, on average. In fact, it appears to serve European public opinion pretty well. Decision-making in some EU institutions may well be complex and difficult to monitor – we are talking about coordinating almost 30 independent states – but saying that the EU is an entirely democracy-free zone appears grossly misleading.

Is the European Parliament representative?

In a recent study I compare the economic policy preferences of voters in the 2009 European Parliament election with the actions taken by national parties between 2009 and 2014 (the 7th European Parliament, EP7). The economic policy preferences (on redistribution, privatisation, and state ownership) of individual European voters were measured from the voter survey of the 2009 European Election Study.

Figure 1 compares the distribution of average party voters’ preferences with the distribution of EP7 national party preferences as retrieved from their written parliamentary questions.

Figure 1: Cumulative distribution functions of party voters’ and EP7 parties’ ideology in economic policy

Note: The dashed line indicates the position of the average voter of each national party included in the analysis. The solid line indicates the ideological positions of all EP7 national parties included in the analysis. The statistical significance of cumulative distribution functions difference was obtained by means of the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test and it amounts to 0.298***.

Figure 1 indicates that average party voters are broadly well represented in the EP. The figure also indicates that there are more political parties in the section slightly left of centre than there are party voters, and that there are more voters in the right-wing section than there are parties. In other words, the average position of European voters slightly left of centre is over-represented by political parties serving in the EP7. At the same time, although the EP7 very accurately represented the middle of the 2009 party voters’ ideological distribution, parties representing extreme voters, appear to have moved towards the centre, leaving some ideological positions without representation, especially on the economic right.

This ‘move away’ from some average party voters (especially extreme ones) towards the median voter is not different from what has been found in many established Western democracies. According to majoritarianism, the ‘median’ voter does tend to be over-represented in a democracy, as it should be. The European Parliament – and, by logical extension, the EU – is not a ‘democracy-free zone’.

Are some voters better represented than others?

Very broadly, political representation theory highlights two main explanations for the failure of some politicians to represent their voters’ preferences. The first explanation relates to the ‘political agency model’ of representative democracies, which emphasises the need for complete and perfect information for good political representation. The second is associated with participatory and Marxist models of democracy, which emphasise accurate descriptive representation, and/or equality in political participation.

An individual-level regression model was designed to test the theories briefly outlined above. ‘Flawed’ representation is here defined as incongruence, i.e. the absolute distance between individual voters and the political parties they voted for in the 2009 election. Figures 2 and 3 provide an overview of the most important results.

Figure 2: Predicted incongruence of political parties due to ‘bad selection’ and voter ‘extremism’

Note: See the author’s accompanying study for more information.

The regression results confirm that individual voters suffer high levels of incongruence if they vote for a party whose average constituent is far away from them, and if they are ideologically distant from the average European voter. These two variables have very substantial effects on incongruence, especially the variable capturing voter extremism.

They lend credence to the ‘political agency’ theory in that it is important to select political parties whose voter base is close to one’s own ideology to be represented. They further demonstrate how the EP conforms to majoritarian democracy in demonstrating that individual voters farthest away from the average European voter are most incongruent with their party.

Figure 3: Predicted incongruence of political parties by voter information, protest voting behaviour and social class

Note: See the author’s accompanying study for more information.

The regression results further lend credence to the political agency theory in that informational disconnect between voters and parties increase incongruence between the individual voter and their party, while social class does not seem to matter.

Social class differences in political participation and in the composition of parliaments have previously been documented. However, these structural disadvantages of the working classes do not seem to lead to higher incongruence at the European Parliament level. If anything, the upper classes seem to suffer from slightly higher incongruence. The social class non-finding is heartening, given the class biases in political representation that have been documented in established democracies.

Implications

The above demonstrates that majoritarian democracy is reflected in the legislative politics of the EU. Written parliamentary questions are one of the most popular forms of legislative activity in the European Parliament. They represent an avenue through which any MEP can communicate with EU executives and through which they can push an issue into the EU policy-making agenda.

The analysis shows that the average European is very well represented in these ‘inputs’ to the EU political system, and that representation flaws are due to voters’ extremism, to voters not voting appropriately (e.g. selecting a party that is ideologically ‘far’ from them, or engaging in second-order/protest voting) or to voters not following the European Parliament election campaign. Social group biases due to structural inequalities are not at all evident.

The EP does not have a representation deficit: where there is incongruence, it is due to voters not being able to select the appropriate party. This further indicates that EP elections need reform: the era of ‘second-order elections’ and national governments running EP election campaigns must end if we want to counteract the information gaps between MEPs and citizens.

______

Note: A longer version was originally published on our sister site LSE EUROPP.

About the author

Miriam Sorace is a Fellow in the European Institute at the LSE.

 

All articles posted on this blog give the views of the author(s), and not the position of LSE British Politics and Policy, nor of the London School of Economics and Political Science. Featured image credit: © European Union 2017 – European Parliament (CC BY-NC-ND 2.0)

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

About the author

Blog Admin

Posted In: Brexit | Featured | LSE Comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *