LSE - Small Logo
LSE - Small Logo

BPP Team

February 11th, 2016

From the Industrial Revolution onward, predictions of calamitous technological change keep missing the mark

3 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

BPP Team

February 11th, 2016

From the Industrial Revolution onward, predictions of calamitous technological change keep missing the mark

3 comments

Estimated reading time: 5 minutes

Technology is widely considered the main source of economic progress, but it has generated cultural anxiety throughout history. Here, Joel Mokyr, Chris Vickers and Nicolas Ziebarth place today’s angst about technological change in a historical context. They emphasize that today’s worries are not new to the modern era and that understanding the history provides perspective on whether this time is truly different.

Luddites

In a recent paper, we place today’s angst about technological change in a historical context. In particular, we study three prominent concerns: (1) Will technological progress cause a substitution of machines for labour and lead to widespread unemployment; (2) Will technology lead to a dehumanisation of work; and (3) Are the days of strong economic growth behind us? We first look at how accurate the predictions of contemporary economists were on these issues, and then what lessons their successes and failures have for today’s prognosticators.

Economists during the Industrial Revolution were divided over whether technological progress would lead to lower employment. Most distinguished between short-term dislocations and longer term, chronic unemployment. Even optimists such as John Stuart Mill and David Ricardo conceded the possibility of short-term unemployment, while others such as Thomas Mortimer believed machines could remove the men from the labour force more permanently. Given the hand wringing over the possibility of technological unemployment, one might have expected it to be a serious problem in the economy of the day, yet there is scant evidence of widespread, long-term idle labour. Indeed, the complaints were rather about rapidly expanding factories and long hours and child labour. Where the case for historical pessimism is stronger is in wages rather than unemployment per se. By some accounts, living standards failed to rise until the middle of the 19th century, decades after the beginning of the Industrial Revolution.

After largely disappearing in the late 19th century, the Great Depression brought a revival of concerns about “surplus” labour, worries which similarly disappeared after the return of economic growth. While the fretting of some contemporary economists about widespread idleness were largely wrong, the costs borne by displaced people were real and far from negligible, with wages for laborers by many estimates taking more than a working lifetime to have risen to reflect rising productivity.

The second source of angst we address is the alleged dehumanisation of work brought on by technological progress. Even Adam Smith, while extolling the efficiency of the division of labour, worried about the deleterious effects of simple, repetitive work. Factory discipline came to replace a more informal, and arguably more flexible method of labour organisation of independent artisans, and much of the factory work itself was dangerous and gruesome. What is striking about these arguments is the degree to which many of them are the inverse of modern anxieties. While today’s pessimists decry the uncertainty associated with the gig economy, the move from independent artisans to factories and a routinised workday was traumatic in its own way. Workers were dissatisfied by the highly structured and regimented nature of factory work and the imposition of discipline through fines and penalties. We see little reason to doubt that workers can adjust to workforce patterns that arguably mirror pre-industrial ones.

Finally, a number of modern writers such as Tyler Cowen or Robert Gordon have suggested something of the reverse view, asserting that the days of rapid technological progress are behind us. This worry, too, is nothing new historically. John Stuart Mill wrote about a “stationary state” during the Industrial Revolution. The Great Depression saw an outbreak of similar pessimism. One notable exception is John Maynard Keynes, whose famous essay “Economic Possibilities of our Grandchildren” predicted that by 2030, our most pressing problem would be how to occupy our leisure time after a century of economic growth.

The overarching point we would emphasize is that today’s worries are not new to the modern era and that understanding the history provides perspective on whether this time is truly different. We are skeptical about the more extreme of modern anxieties about long-term, ineradicable technological unemployment or a widespread lack of meaning because of changes in work patterns. Predictions about unemployment are often based on looking at only process innovation, missing the more important long-term trends in the invention of entirely new products, and the jobs that come with these. While making specific predictions about the future of technology is imprudent, we are sceptical about an end to major innovation any time soon, particularly with scientists and researchers having access to increasingly powerful tools and sources of data to build on previous discoveries.

We emphasize that the transition paths to the economy of the future may be quite painful for some industries and workers, as these transitions tend to be. One difference from earlier transitions, particularly the Industrial Revolution, is that, much more than in the past, public policy may be used to ameliorate the harsher effects of dislocation in welfare states. Direct income redistribution could supplement the income of some classes of workers. A complementary strategy would be to increase the set of publicly provided goods. However, we should not let these real worries about dislocations unduly distract us from the overarching lessons of the least two centuries of history, which were ones of technologically driven rising living standards and largely failed predictions of eminent calamity.

___

Notes: this post originally appeared on LSE Business Review and is based on the paper The History of Technological Anxiety and the Future of Economic Growth: Is This Time Different?,  Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 29, Number 3 — Summer 2015 — Pages 31–50.

About the Authors

Joel MokyrJoel Mokyr is Robert H. Strotz Professor of Arts and Sciences and Professor of Economics and History, Northwestern University since 1974. He is also Sackler Professorial Fellow, Eitan Berglas School of Economics, University of Tel Aviv.

 

Chris VickersChris Vickers is Assistant Professor of Economics at Auburn University, Alabama. He joined the department in 2013 after finishing his Ph.D. at Northwestern University. Dr. Vickers’ research interests are in economic history and applied microeconomics.

 

nicolas ziebarthNicolas Ziebarth is an Assistant Professor in the Tippie College of Business at the University of Iowa. He obtained his PhD in Economics from Northwestern University. Dr Ziebarth was a finalist for the Economic History Association’s Nevins Prize in 2012, received a Sokoloff Graduate Fellowship in 2011 and a Robert Eisner Memorial Fellowship, Northwestern University, in 2011.

Featured image credit: Luddites Later interpretation of machine breaking (1812) – Public Domain

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

About the author

BPP Team

Posted In: Economy and Society | Featured

3 Comments

Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported
This work by British Politics and Policy at LSE is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported.